The individual rationality of buying small cokes/chippies
One of the most vexing questions in economics has to be why the price of a 330ml coke is often only slightly less than the price of a 1.5l coke. This issue generalises to other products such as chippies.
Now there are a number of good responses, namely:
- Strongly diminishing marginal utility for fresh coke and a very low value on saved coke (or a relatively high cost of storage),
- A 330ml bottle is easier to consume than a 1.5l bottle – as a result the value of the 330ml bottle may be higher for people on the move, and so they are priced to service different markets.
- The cost of producing a 330ml coke is far more than a 33/150th of the cost of producing a 1.5l coke
These answers seem to satisfy me when I think of coke. However, when I think of chippies I find this explanation sadly lacking.
Downstairs I can buy a little bag of chippies for $1.50 or a far bigger bag of chippies (x3) for $3.00. I always buy the little bag.
Now I will do this each day, and don’t get any less value from 3 day old chippies than I do fresh chippies. Furthermore, I am eating them at work – implying that there is no storage cost and no convenience benefit.
No-one steals my chippies if I get a big packet so its not that. Am I passing up a free lunch here (and thereby not being a utility maximiser as my shirt says) – or is there a reason I buy the small bag instead of the big bag.
Other reasons for choosing small
There is actually a reason why I buy the small bag instead of the big bag – marginal pricing and pre-commitment.
Even though the big bag is three times the size of the small bag it does not imply that I will consume those chips over three days. When I have a whole big bag of chips in front of me I just consume them until the marginal cost of doing so is equal to the marginal benefit. As the marginal cost is virtually zero, I keep consuming until I get zero or negative satisfaction from an additional chip.
If I buy a smaller bag of chips then I introduce a cost for eating past that point. So for example, even if the small bag was 1/3 of the cost of the big bag, it is likely that I would still end up eating less chips – as I have to pay to get each 1/3.
The optimality of this relies on the assumption that the last set of chips I eat (say for simplicity I would eat the whole big bag – then we are talking about the last 1/3) is actually worth less than the appropriate proportion of the price (1/3 in the example case). This is me paying for the introduction of marginal pricing.
On the precommitment side I realise that I am viciously time inconsistent with chippie eating. Before eating the chips I think that the optimal path would be to only eat a few chips. When eating the chips I want all the chips. Once I’ve eaten the chips, I wish I hadn’t, as I’ve got to go and play hockey – damn you hyperbolic discounting!
By buying fewer chips/limiting my choice set I can pre-commit to eating less chippies (h.t. Rose Colligan). As it is my choice to do so prior to the chippy eating game between my past, present, and future selves, I know that the choice will be optimal.
With the advantage of marginal pricing and pre-commitment provide two more reasons why the small packs of chippies and small drinks at the supermarket are not much cheaper than the big ones!
So, the costs of production don’t really come into it. Never mind one is stumping up $1.50 for 45 grams of potato.
The costs of production were mentioned among the initial three points here:
“3 The cost of producing a 330ml coke is far more than a 33/150th of the cost of producing a 1.5l coke”
“Never mind one is stumping up $1.50 for 45 grams of potato”
Cooked potato mate – I love eating potatoes but I hate cooking them 🙂
My site http://fasterwq.1gb.in/tourism1883.html