Behavioural prejudices

Eric has a post up in which he criticises behavioural economics:

Behavioural economics usually leaves a bad taste in my mouth. Too much of it just feels like …it was done in the 50s and 60s.

Essentially, his problem with the field appears to be that its results are often used to rationalise paternalism. I don’t have time to respond in detail now but my first thoughts are:

  • Don’t dismiss results just because you don’t like the potential implications or the messenger. That would be like me saying I don’t like the Coase theorem just because it’s constantly misused by libertarians.
  • There is a big difference between disliking a result and disliking the conclusions that some people draw from it.
  • Behavioural economics is a very young field so it’s not surprising that it feels like mainstream economics from fifty years ago. It hasn’t yet matured into a coherent framework, but we should encourage practitioners to move in that direction, rather than dismissing it for lack of maturity.
  • The research in behavioural economics has, until recently, been spearheaded by psychologists so it isn’t necessarily tightly tied to the sort of framework economists use. That’s not a problem, it’s an opportunity for economists!
  • The youth of the field and its present empirical focus mean that it often feels very piecemeal. At the very least, it certainly doesn’t have the monolithic feel of mainstream choice theory. It’s hard to say whether economists will be able to tie it all together into as satisfying a framework as standard choice theory, but the lack of an overarching theory doesn’t make it wrong. It may be that economists eventually just have to accept that their field is becoming more fragmented, which just reflects the difficulty of accurately describing human choices.

I’ll return to some of these themes over the course of the week as I have more time.

6 replies
  1. Eric Crampton
    Eric Crampton says:

    We aren’t providing advice to benevolent despots, James. 

    I’m not saying dismiss behavioural results. I’m saying that we should set a high bar on providing policy advice based on those results. Lab experiment results ought to be confirmed by field experiments. And we ought to have a close eye on comparative institutional analysis: will the bureaucrats running the programme be less subject to behavioural failings?

    Behavioural econ can give some great advice as in self-help books – things to watch for in your day to day decision making. I get nervous when it’s applied too quickly to policy-making. Especially when you can point to a purported lab behavioural failing to ex post justify just about any damned thing you like.

    • jamesz
      jamesz says:

      I wholly agree that you can’t point to a cognitive bias and then say it justifies intervention. That’s like pointing to the failure of the conditions for Pareto optimality and then saying one should obviously intervene. However, that feels more like a critique of policy-makers, rather than an indictment on behavioural economists.

      In many ways, behavioural economics feels like primary data gathering at the moment, rather than a mature theory that could be used to justify intervention. It’s natural that people will seize on some results to justify their prejudices, but we shouldn’t let that hinder the progress of the science!

      • Eric Crampton
        Eric Crampton says:

        … and that’s why it worries me when a not insubstantial proportion of papers in behavioural economics draw policy implications without considering comparative institutional analysis….

        I’m not saying that we should shut down the behavioural programme. Rather, we should be a bit more reticent to advance any policy conclusions from it until it’s matured a bit. 

  2. Richard
    Richard says:

    <i>  It hasn’t yet matured into a coherent framework, but we should encourage practitioners to move in that direction </i>
    Does it need to if it’s delivering evidence via  (lab and field) experiments?  

    • jamesz
      jamesz says:

      Good question, and one that I’m probably not qualified to answer. Matt probably has some deep and meaningful thoughts on the matter, but I’d say yes. Forming a consistent model of choice allows us to generalise beyond the experiment. Essentially, we want to be able to abduce from the results of the experiment the reasons for the behaviour we observe. From there we can make predictions about other behaviours and use our model to draw conclusions that can’t be deduced from the experiment itself.

      • Richard
        Richard says:

        I generally agree but I guess why I ask this about behavioural economics in particular is that the application of broader models to to specific human behaviours is that that is where things have gone so very very wrong.  I suspect we’d be better off in many cases if we asked how will this intervention work out and tested the relevant behaviours robustly rather than drawing too long a bow from other models. 
         

Comments are closed.