Political equilibrium, OBR, and deposit insurance

There has been some discussion of deposit insurance, the open bank resolution plan, and the types of risks being faced by New Zealand savers.  This is actually a hugely important issue, and as a broad matter of principle I actually find myself agreeing more with Labour and the Greens than National and the Reserve Bank.  My view is that deposit insurance should be announced, it should be explicit, there should be certainty around it, and it should be treated as a form of “compulsory insurance” with the payment of an associated “insurance levy on debt financing” for financial institutions over a certain size.  Of course, even with this the OBR still has a place (it is actually a very separate issue) – and that is why the RBNZ was right in saying this.

In order to see why this is the conclusion I’ve drawn, one that differs from current policy, let’s have a brief look at my thought process through a post.

Political equilibrium, credibility, and expectations

Bailouts are a topic that the government, Treasury, and the RBNZ are justifiably wanting to avoid talking about too much in public.  Why this is justifiable, but the reason why we may need to be more transparent about it, comes from thinking about the expectations of people both within and outside of a bank run.

Governments and central banks are perceived by people in the economy to be the lender of last resort – due to a view on bank runs.  Having a functioning lender of last resort means that, in the worst case scenario, these institutions will act as a lender of last resort.  In this way, the NZ government is expected to bail out large financial institutions (in the NZ case banks) if they fail.

Now on the face of it we might not like this.  We don’t bail out other large companies.  And with an implicit backstop, financial institutions will take on too much risk (and the people funding these institutions will assume there is far less risk) – this is the problem of moral hazard.  In this way, the expectation of a bailout creates a difference between the “full social riskiness” associated with lending and the risk that private individuals and firms face when deciding to lend and borrow between each other, through a bank.

The Treasury, government, and RBNZ acknowledge this moral hazard issue – and so they want to introduce the open bank resolution policy settings as a way of avoiding bank runs (which is why we have deposit insurance in the first place), insuring the bankruptcy is orderly for financial institutions (to make the costs to everyone involved, from negotiating about who gets what, as small as possible), and limiting the number of situations where “bailouts” will really be required.

This is good, this is exactly what they should do.  However, the scheme lacks three things when it comes to thinking about “expectations”:

  1. Clarity about how losses are determined and split in a typical situation that requires bankruptcy – an issue that will be solved soon.
  2. Clarity around how this links to the lender of last resort function of the central bank.
  3. The political incentives to bailout banks.

Let us be honest here.  The government will not let a bank fail.  They will not let depositors lose money.  It is in the government’s interest during a bank failure to have taxpayers pick up the tab.  People know that the government will do this (or at least form expectations based on this) as so will lend to banks in a way where they are seen as riskless!  There is an implicit deposit guarantee scheme for banks at the moment!  This is the key point – even if we aren’t admitting it, there is a deposit guarantee running at present that we aren’t acknowledging.

As a result, it makes sense to turn around and make this explicit.  Note:  If the government thinks it can costlessly credibly commit to not bailing out institutions, and the RBNZ can solve the issue of bank runs without full deposit insurance, then this is good.  But we do not have that right now, not in the slightest, and it should be admitted as policy relevant.

This doesn’t seem particularly fair on the taxpayers

No it doesn’t.  According to most free instant cash advance apps, the tax payer is essentially subsidising loans.  The subsidy is then split between depositors, the banks, and the borrow due to relative elasticities, information, and bargaining positions.  Overall “too much” is invested due to what is socially optimal … this is where we have the “too much debt” business.

If we make the deposit guarantee explicit instead of implicit and we completely remove the loss from default – if anything it will exacerbate the moral hazard issue issue!  So what do we do?

Deposit guarantees are a form of insurance.  Generally, you pay for insurance with an insurance levy.  If we have an explicit guarantee scheme on deposits, then there should be a levy on those deposits.

Yes this will reduce investment, yes this will see lower returns to depositors, but without doing this we have a deposit guarantee scheme that just costs everyone in NZ and in turn makes the entire financial system more unstable.

The kicker with all this is that the insurance scheme will have to be compulsory for all institutions over some type of nominal size.  The type of bank failure we are concerned about, and which will lead to bail outs, stems from an episode where there is systemic risk to the banking sector as a whole.  In that case the incentive to take on the insurance for an individual firm does not match the full social return associated with it.  Furthermore, if the bank decides to take on insurance it may be seen as a signal of weakness (given asymmetric information) making banks unwilling to take on the insurance for signaling reasons.  Finally, the political eqm argument suggests that a government may well bail out the bank irrespective of whether they have taken on the insurance – making a bank unwilling to pay for insurance they can expect to get anyway.

Conclusion

At the moment there are two ways forward when thinking about banking policy in NZ:

  1. Explicit deposit insurance, with an associated deposit levy.
  2. A credible commitment by government that it won’t guarantee deposits combined with RBNZ regulation that can avoid bank runs.

Current policy is trying to push towards the second (which is admirable), but in the current environment I do not believe it is credible given the idea of “political incentives”.  Which is why I find the idea of explicit deposit insurance combined with a deposit levy to be the best way forward.

Note:  Concern about levies is a fair point.  If we are the only country “not subsidising”, what does that mean for us?  I’d note that the big runs here come from trying to introduce this during a crisis – it doesn’t rule out the effectiveness of the policy outside of a crisis.  In a number of ways this would be similar to the FDIC – just with appropriate insurance premiums (which are ex-ante pretty danged hard to determine), and with an appropriate scale to ensure that the government can commit to no more additional bailouts.

Note 2Good post by Eric stating why he thinks the government can commit.

RBNZ cannot bind future governments. But setting up the regime well in advance of a bank failure specifying that, no matter what else happens, the equity and (subordinated) bond holders get burned first gives those agents reasonable expectation that they should try to make sure that doesn’t happen. If some future government defects by bailing out depositors, I’d expect it to happen only after burning through the equity and bondholders.

Note 3The Economist points out research by the IMF that shows explicit deposit insurance makes the moral hazard problem more acute – this is a pretty easy to understand idea, and we mentioned the concept above (just under our second subtitle).  This is why we both require a levy, and have to accept that it is “inefficient” relative to a situation where the government commits to not bailing out banks AND we have a way to prevent bank runs (where by this I mean optimally reduce the probability of a bank run so the expected cost of it happening is equal to the expected cost of introducing preventative measures).  If we can do that second bit – then do it, and scrap the compulsory insurance.

Bubbles, FDI, winners and losers

I’m so sorry I am still away – currently a bit caught up!  I will be back posting properly and answering comments in a few days.

For now, here is the latest article I’ve popped up on Rates Blog.

In it I discuss what it means for there to be a “bubble” due to foriegn investment, and I mull over long-term foriegn investment.  I am relatively terse in the article, this probably stems from my lack of sleep and the fact I’m busy 😉

I conclude:

Foreign investment and the associated capital flows have been a net positive for New Zealand in the past.

Let’s not forget this as we try to figure out what policy to set in a post-Global Financial Crisis world.

I have no doubt that this article will be unpopular with close to everyone.  That is fine.

“Living wage a test of small business’ mettle”

Via Stuff this morning, great quotes from FIRST union leader Robert Reid:

“Why should a worker suffer for being employed by a business that maybe shouldn’t exist,”

As the debate about the living wage continues, we get yet another indication that unions are fine with unemployment – as their clients aren’t the unemployed.

Dom Stephens from Westpac (NZ’s 17th sexiest economist) is quoted further down in the article and rebuts things nicely, so I will just leave it there:

Large increases lifting the minimum wage above where the free market put it – “and I think it [proposed living wage] may be moving toward that” – very clearly affected employment, Stephens said. “It would worsen things for the most vulnerable members of society and improve the lot of those who stayed employed.”

 

Keeping it all together on bond sales

Hey all, I’ve been away – and I still am.  I’ll be back next week.  However, I have to write on this.  Over on Rates Blog, Bernard Hickey stated the following:

The most interesting revelation from today’s Monetary Policy Statement was Graeme Wheeler’s comment that he knew other central banks were buying New Zealand government bonds as part of their Reserve buying programmes.

This is how printed money is lifting our currency to over-valued levels.

Ok, now I don’t know what the RBNZ has been saying – I don’t go to their media lock-up.  But lets think through this a bit.

“Bond buying” will push up the currency if there is some sort of financial flow – such as the government increasing borrowing (and it being funded from overseas) or bond holders in NZ selling bonds to overseas buyers.  From what is indicated, it seems like we’ve had a bit of both.  So the government is borrowing to pay for a bunch of stuff, and this is increasing the current account deficit.  We need a corresponding lift in the capital account surplus to pay for it – hence we have this financial inflow.  People are willing to lend to us incredibly cheaply so this is pretty nice of them.

The two complaints I’m hearing are:

  1. It pushes up the dollar:  Investment+consumption > savings, so yes this pushes up the dollar.  The question is why the interest rate and exchange rates that puts us in our current “balance” seem so high relative to other countries.  Is it because our growth prospects are better?  If so this is good.  Is it because of some structural issues in our economy?  If so this could be bad.  Is it because, as the RBNZ seems to believe, there is a bubble in the dollar/bond markets – if so we have people overpaying New Zealander’s to buy bonds that will decline in price … interesting.
  2. Why don’t we print/pay for it domestically:  This is part of the “QE for NZ” crew view, and it is inappropriate.  Keep the ideas together here, what are we trying to “solve” by getting the central bank to buy government bonds?  Are we trying to loosen monetary conditions … if so cut interest rates, as QE is really a form of this.  Are we trying to reduce foriegn lending … if so we need to reduce domestic borrowing, we are a small open economy and so we pay the world interest rate to borrow as much as we want (in a sense).  If monetary conditions are appropriate, then QE will just be inflationary, and it does nothing about the inherent “savings-investment imbalance” that people are concerned about when they discuss people lending to NZers.

Remember, we can “overlabel”

Following the unfortunate death of a woman from drinking far too much Coke, there have been calls to label Coke.  I’m all for information, and that often makes me pro-labeling, but in this case I’m not … it is important to recognise that we are targeting providing information, and so we can “overlabel”.

A label gives information as an abstract concept, but it is costly to interpret and so the existence of a label is often taken as a signal, and used as a rule of thumb.  As a result, too much labeling of things could reduce the true information content – leading to people making more poorly informed decisions.

The solution?  There is a trade-off for the amount we label a given piece of food etc – and we need to accept that.  However, we can also make more detailed information and standards a necessary requirement to be on some sort of central website – so people who do want to take into account greater information can do so at a low cost.  I would also note that people that design easier to interpret labels which don’t sacrifice information are “shifting out the information curve” – this is a real productivity improvement, and these people are cool as a result.

The overall goal of the regulation is to “maximise information” so that people can take costs and benefits into account when they do something.  That should be the guiding principal – not saying people should have one thing or another.

Note:  Look, no need for me to go on about personal responsibility, or insult the woman about her life choice to get this result – which I’ve seen a bunch of.  We don’t know her life, preferences, or situation – so we shouldn’t suddenly decide that since it is a choice we wouldn’t make we should either ban the product or attack the choice.  I’ve noticed a lot of both, and its generally a bit disrespectful, which is also why I delayed this post until people stopped being rude.

Quote of the day: On bank subsidies

Via this excellent review by John Cochrane, I decided to read “the banker’s new clothes“.  I’m only a small way in, but it already seem like a pretty good book, written for a non-technical type of audience.  Excellent.

My view has been that there is potentially some type of externality from bank’s actions (systemic risk stemming from asymmetric information and potentially linkages), and that there has been a implicit subsidy to  deal with this – and so the clearest solution would be to treat the lender of last resort function as enforced insurance … and make banks pay an insurance premium (*,*).

The book is taking a very similarish line, although it is focusing on capital ratios.  Essentially, banks become highly leveraged because debt is lower risk than capital funding when they go to borrow (as bondholders will get bailed out, but equity holders won’t) – so they appear to be pushing towards (as Cochrane is) much higher minimum capital ratios.  I would note that this is where the NZ Reserve Bank has been pushing regulation since prior to the crisis (to prove this I was looking for a paper I saw from 1999 … and ran into this bulletin from 1996!), and a number of measures have been introduced or are close.  By default I prefer price to quantity mechanisms, but I’m leaving myself open to be persuaded by the book.

In any case, the quote.  Here:

Subsidizing banks to borrow excessively and take on so much risk that the entire banking system is threatened is like subsidizing and encouraging companies to pollute when they have clean alternatives

On thing missing in the quote is the cost – we haven’t pinned down the true relative price for clean vs non-clean.  But adding a subsidy in the face of an externality is peverse, and is a good motivator for looking at the issue.