Is housing affordability the issue?

The productivity commission has released its final report on “housing affordability”.  Now there are a number of important points in the report, and there are undeniable issues in the New Zealand housing market which have caused a “misallocation” of resources.

However, the justification for their being a housing affordability issue in the report is not fully covered off – something that is surprising given that this is the issue that appears in the title of the report.

Read more

More NZ economics blogs

Given recent hectic times I’ve neglected to mention a couple of new New Zealand economics blogs.

There is Fair play and forward passes (via Anti-Dismal), where an economics lecturer from Massey discusses sports and New Zealand economics.

There is also Welly Gnome, where a Vic University undergrad takes it upon himself to get into economics blogging.

I of course encourage everyone studying, teaching, and practicing economics in New Zealand to start blogging – see it as a way for us to communicate ideas.  In the end it might not be for everyone, but I think its an important way of getting discourse regarding the New Zealand economy (which is at times lacking).

Some people might be worried that there would be too much “noise” – so that whatever is good won’t get through.  Given how few economics blogs currently exist in New Zealand I would say that, even if  the worst case scenario where the noise of a million screaming economists drowns out any useful information is what would happen, we are a long long way away from that now …

Hot cross buns … a lesson on pricing

Over on his blog, Bill Bennett has been discussing hot cross bun inflation over the last couple of hundred years – saying that it has averaged about 1.1%pa.

With the consumption of hot cross buns about to spike, I thought I would copy and paste my comments on hot cross bun pricing over here:

One thing I’d note though is that the increase in the price level more generally only really got kicking off during the last 50 or so years. As a result, if hot cross buns had just been generally following inflation overall, the 1.1%pa figure could be a bit misleading.

Another point when looking at hot cross buns – we need to ask what the price of these buns has done relative to all other goods and services. Over the past 200 and a bit years we have seen the relative price of inputs fall for hot cross buns, but we have also seen incomes rise – and given that hot cross buns are a “normal good” it is ambiguous whether hot cross bun inflation has exceeded inflation in goods and in prices.

A final point, a hot cross bun in 1798 would have tasted and felt different than a current hot cross bun – any changes in the quality of said bun should be taken into account.

These are all points to keep in mind when looking at changes in the price of any good or service.

On GST and regressivity

James did an excellent post discussing tax issues recently.  After this, he obtained a copy of the book, and dug out the three ways that Rob Salmond had noted GST was regressive.  It is good to see Rob put some thought into it and found measurable reasons why regressivity exists – but I also need to point out where I disagree.

In essence, of the three reasons for regressivity I believe that only one is regressive (and by less than we may expect), that one is neutral, and that one of the reasons actually makes GST a progressive tax.

The reasons Rob outlines are:

  • Some savings are spent on acquiring multiple properties, which do not attract GST
  • Some savings are spent outside of New Zealand, which also do not attract GST
  • Some people do not spend all their savings before they die. That is, they are lifetime net savers.

Importantly, all of these forms of GST-exempt dispersal of savings are more likely among wealthy people than among poor people.

My response (with a bunch of arbitrary notes thrown in) was:

  1. The construction of a house attracts GST, so it is just the rental and “owner occupied rental” that doesn’t.  As rich households tend to spend a lower proportion of their income on rent this is progressive.  Remember in turn that this “rental” price is also related to the replacement cost of the house … part of the reason for not including rent in GST is the impression that we would be double taxing it!
  • [Note on this first point – I wrote it with regards solely to the ownership of a house, not multiple properties – as that is how I read the initial question.  Even so, it isn’t clear that implied rental expenditure as a % of income rises by decline – I will have to investigate. [Huzzah, investigation done, the share of expenditure on housing of total expenditure falls as the income decile rises.]]
  1. Having GST rather than income tax leads to a one off increase in the price level, which lowers the value of the New Zealand dollar.  This pushes up the cost of goods and services overseas in the near term – given convergence towards the PPP level.  Overall, I still think this will be a regressive element though.
  • [Note:  Looking at the HES data, spending overseas as a % of total spending is surprisingly constant among income declines … making it seem like a pretty neutral impact at present.]
  1. Although more wealthy people will leave proportionally larger bequests, bequests only have value in so far as the next generation buys goods and services – as a result, they will be taxed, and this is neutral.

I would also note that, even if all of these elements were “regressive” we would need to look at representative baskets by income groups to get an idea of how much of an impact that would make – and given that GST exists, this will be exaggerated by the fact that people are choosing volumes to consumer based on the “lower relative price” of anything where the GST burden does not fall.

Comments and discussion welcome – tax is a huge issue, with fascinating equity and efficiency considerations running through it.

Bleg: What is the issue endogenous money people are after?

I have a question where I would love some help 🙂

Via Marginal Revolution I noticed that there seems to be quite a war between economists regarding the financial sector.

However, I actually don’t see where there is an issue in the argument that is going on.  The way I see it Nick Rowe has it right with his comments here and here, and in turn this illustrates that even though a central bank doesn’t explicitly constrain the “stock” or the “supply” of money, their cash rate (and its relation to the natural rate) and inflation target (given an output gap view of the evolution of inflation) provide an implicit constraint.

The way I see it, mainstream theory and “endogenous money” theory people can both assume that the quantity and/or supply of money is endogenous, and that investment=savings-current account.  So where is the difference, what does it tell us, and how is it testable?

Prices, rents, and costs

The NBR has pointed to an article to the Economist that shows house price to income and house price to rent ratios – pointing out that the very high house price to rent ratio can be used as an indicator that the return on housing is very low/house prices are heavily overvalued.

Now one criticism that people may raise is that the “quality” of the housing stock and the rental stock has changed – and so the relative prices/spending from income could indeed change.  However, the Economist uses figures from Quotable Value New Zealand (as well as Stats NZ) – and so the quality of housing is in fact taken into account in these indices! [Note:  It is not necessarily clear the categories are comparable – so this argument could still be used]

As a result, we could say that this is true – the return for an investor in the housing market seems pretty low.

But what else can we tell from all this?  Relative to historic averages, the price to rent ratio is 68% higher, and the price to income ratio is 20% higher.  So this implies that price/rent is 168% of its average, and price/income is 120% of its average … which tells us that rent/income is 71% of its long-run average.  If we believe these figures, the rental cost … the cost of actually consuming a housing service relative to income … is very low! [Update:   So this is consistent with rising living standards, and having to spend less on housing services – a nice foil to all the suggestions that housing costs have been eating into incomes!]

I’m not sure how much I trust these figures overall, price to rent ratios in this index has been rising constantly over the last 40 years implying that there may be a “quality adjustment” issue in the data to me.

However, if we do use these figures to say that house prices are too high – they also tell us that rents are too low.  Any explanation we have needs to explain both of these parts of the data.  [Update:  This is not clear from the data – and is actually a misleading statement, so just ignore it.  In truth, we need to ask how much of the adjustment will occur through rents and how much through prices]